Romola Sanyal and Mara Ferreri Platform economies and urban planning: Airbnb and regulated deregulation in London Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Sanyal, Romola and Ferreri, Mara (2018) Platform economies and urban planning: Airbnb and regulated deregulation in London. Urban Studies. ISSN 0042-0980 DOI: 10.1177/0042098017751982 © 2018 Urban Studies Journal Limited This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/87473/ Available in LSE Research Online: April 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. Authors' final version. Published as Ferreri, M and Sanyal, R (2018) Platform economies and urban planning: Airbnb and regulated deregulation in London, Urban Studies. First Published February 28, 2018, https://doi.org/10.1177/0042098017751982 Platform economies and urban planning: Airbnb and regulated deregulation in London Abstract The ‘sharing economy’ has become a new buzzword in urban life as digital technology companies set up online platforms to link together people and un- or underutilised assets with those seeking to rent them for short periods of time. While cloaked under the rhetoric of ‘sharing’, the exchanges they foster are usually profit-driven. These economic activities are having profound impacts on urban environments as they disrupt traditional forms of hospitality, transport, service industry and housing. While critical debates have focused on the challenges that sharing economy activities bring to existing labour and economic practices, it is necessary to acknowledge that they also have increasingly significant impacts on planning policy and urban governance. Using the case of Airbnb in London, this article looks at how these sharing or platform economy companies are involved in encouraging governments to change existing regulations, in this case by deregulating short-term letting. This has important implications for planning enforcement. We examine how the challenges around obtaining data to enforce new regulations are being addressed by local councils who struggle to balance corporate interests with public good. Finally, we address proposals for using algorithms and big data as means of urban governance and argue that the schism between regulation and enforcement is opening up new digitally mediated spaces of informal practices in cities. Keywords Data, governance, housing, planning, sharing economy, technology/smart cities Introduction In London, as well as other major Airbnb cities, rather than arriving to a home-cooked meal served up by a hospitable individual, you could well find yourself renting a flat run by a third-party management company, and collecting your keys from an agent who lets out hundreds of other properties for hosts who are less interested in cross-cultural connections and more concerned with collecting their money at the end of the month. (Coldwell, 2016) The sharing economy has gained popularity in a number of cities across the world and has opened up new avenues of living and working, particularly since the global economic recession of 2008 (Killick, 2015). Digital technology companies, often backed by venture capital, have created platforms through which people can share unused or underused goods and services with those seeking to use them for short periods of time. It has been argued that this is part of a wider set of seismic changes to the ways in which economic activities take place in cities across the globe towards more flexible and on-demand forms of work and living (Riley, 2012).The claim of facilitating more collective and convivial ways of accessing and utilising assets and services is beginning to have an impact on policy-making. Local and national governments have been keen to engage with the sharing economy to not only harness its potential, but also to be seen to embrace new ways of living and working. While appealing in theory, critics have noted that this benign veneer hides more complex workings of digitally mediated ‘sharing’ that replicate and reinforce existing dynamics of property ownership and capitalist relations (Killick, 2015). Cities have become key sites for the development of digitally mediated sharing, and particularly of short-term letting which straddles the divide between housing and hospitality. Airbnb, one of the most wellknown and controversial of these platforms, has rapidly gained a monopolistic position in many cities around the globe (Jefferson-Jones, 2014). In its publicity campaigns, the company has repeatedly emphasised how it enables sharing the home of a local resident and enjoying an ‘authentic’ experience of place; yet it does so through a profit-driven foundational logic as compared with a socially driven one. It claims to offer property owners the ability to maximise the utility of their underused assets such as rooms, entire flats or other properties. As such, critical commentators have argued that it is not part of the ‘pure’ sharing economy as much as the corporate-driven process that involves increased utilisation of durable assets (Finck and Ranchordas, 2016; Schor, 2014). Thanks to the visibility of such critique, the question of regulating ‘sharing economy’ letting platforms has increasingly become a topic of debate, particularly in cities facing pressure on space due to tourism on the one hand and affordable housing needs on the other (van der Zee, 2016). While scholarly debates have mainly focused on the economics of short-term letting and on the challenges it poses to established hospitality industries and forms of labour (Cockayne, 2016; Edelman and Geradin, 2015; Schor, 2014), less emphasis has been placed on how the activities and uses facilitated by ‘sharing’ platforms are remaking spaces and territorial governance. This paper aims to address this gap by focusing on the under-examined impact of the sharing economy on urban governance, and particularly on planning. Against an imaginary of deterritorialised global uses, the new economic practices mediated by digital platforms are met with geographically specific pre-existing planning policies and practices of regulation and enforcement. Drawing on secondary sources, policy documents and qualitative interviews with planning officers about the regulation of Airbnb in London, UK, we analyse policy shifts and practices of enforcement at local government level and examine how emerging digitally mediated uses of space usher in both new urban regulations and unexpected challenges to their enforcement, raising wider questions about the role of information technology companies in transforming city governance across the globe. Urban planning policy and the challenges of the sharing economy The Sharing Economy is a movement: it is a movement for deregulation. (Slee, 2016: 26) Since the ‘sharing economy’ entered wider public discourse in 2011, it has been celebrated as the new frontier of economic innovation and as capable of disrupting existing industries as well as ways of life. Within its ‘contrasting and contradictory framings’ (Martin, 2016), the narrative of economic opportunity has become increasingly dominant. The growth of the sector has been presented as desirable and necessary as it fosters the micro-entrepreneurialism of individual monetising underutilised assets alongside being ‘a major commercial opportunity for entrepreneurs, companies, industries and/or countries’ (Martin, 2016: 153). This celebration has found fertile ground in the established ‘enterprise discourse’ and attempts at regulating the sector were initially portrayed by advocates as unnecessary ‘red tape’. The strong binary opposition between innovation and control has been argued to be central to neoliberal discourse: ‘on the side of freedom and prosperity are the qualities of enterprise, initiative, self-reliance and their outward manifestation: entrepreneurship. Ranged against them, but about to be swept aside, are the evils of progressive taxation, government control and welfarism’ (Armstrong, 2005: 41). In the establishment of the neoliberal project of entrepreneurialism, the transformation of the role of central and local governments has been seen as pivotal (Harvey, 1989;Ward, 2003), and as particularly visible in planning policy deregulation. Critical literature on the impact of neoliberal discourse on urbanism has examined the complicity of governments in shifting and suspending laws and regulation in an attempt to encourage private enterprise and court global corporate investment. Scholars have noted how neoliberalism has been allowed to expand through tactics such as creating zones of exception (Ong, 2006), suspending rules and regulations (Roy, 2009), selectively enforcing them (McFarlane and Waibel, 2012) or replacing them with new policies, legislations and regulators. Rather than the rolling out of a coherent and all-encompassing urban paradigm, however, urban neoliberalism is better thought of as developing in geographically and temporally uneven and variegated ways (Brenner et al., 2010) and as a heterogeneous and non-linear process of neoliberalisation (Peck, 2010), challenging and adapting to but also being resisted through different locally specific socio-economic and political relations (Holman et al., 2017). In this context, it is important to qualify that neoliberal ‘deregulation’ does not equate to the withdrawal or absence of regulation, but should rather be understood in terms of practices of reregulation or ‘regulated deregulation’ (Aalbers, 2016). The notion of regulated deregulation is suggested by Aalbers to clarify and better conceptualise the role of deregulation under neoliberalism as the process by which ‘some economic agents are given greater freedom from state control but the market framework itself is regulated’ (2016: 3). Recent moves by cities around the globe to reshape market rules to enable the proliferation of large digital-led platform economies such as Airbnb could be seen as a prime example of regulated deregulation in planning. Since its founding, Airbnb has developed as rapidly as it has attracted calls for regulation. A key critique of the platform and its ‘sharing’ rhetoric has been that it actually encourages the professional use of the platform and the accumulation of additional property in order to acquire rents. Higher income from short lets encouraged by Airbnb have also incentivized property owners to shift to renting on the platform rather than putting it on the long-term rental market where they would earn less. It has been suggested that these shifts have significant impact on local rental and property markets (Cocola-Gant, 2016) while also circumventing local regulations around safety and taxation (Finck and Ranchordás 2016: 46-7; Levin 2016). Moreover, the use of the platform for vacation rental impinges on the existing hospitality industry, ‘disrupting’ traditional forms of hosting travellers (Guttentag, 2015). Concern around running 'illegal hotels' that circumvent rules and regulations protecting consumers around issues of safety, security and discrimination (Edelman and Luca, 2014) has been used by the established hospitality sector to demand regulation of the presence and expansion of the service. Blurring the boundaries between hospitality and housing, the platform has been affecting urban regulations around both. Governments’ attempts to develop regulatory frameworks to govern the activities of Airbnb have differed across cities and at various scales, in approaches and aims. As Finck and Ranchordás (2016) have noted, at one end of the spectrum are those urban governments that engage in a laissez-faire or minimalist approach. Some of these have attempted to experiment with the process of producing new regulations, collaborating with the platforms, piloting policies, allowing these services to operate temporarily in an attempt to remake their regulatory environments. At the other end are those governments that have used existing planning regulation to restrict or reject the operations of ‘sharing economy’ platforms. As governments engage with the activities mediated by these platforms, they produce and implement changes in urban planning policy and practice that can often reveal contradictory priorities at different levels of government. Regulation and its implementation can become a particular issue for local authorities and planning enforcement officers, who attempt to address the questions of ‘public good’ against a central government that may be more interested in short-term economic gains than longer term attention to social needs (Lord and Tewdwr-Jones, 2014). With the celebration of the sharing economy being dominated by the neoliberal language of entrepreneurship, the question of balancing short-term gains and the wider public good is particularly crucial for the understanding the challenges posed by digital platform economies to planning frameworks and practice. In this paper we analyse the regulatory challenges generated at the level of local planning enforcement by the activities of Airbnb in London as a case of shifting regulations and competing priorities and practices around encouraging ‘sharing’ in cities. To develop our argument, we first analyse the discourse deployed by corporate and state actors to discuss regulation in the ‘sharing economy’, how it informed specific national policy strategies and how these strategies were then embedded into practice at lower levels of urban governance. We argue that the discourse is informed by a ‘flattening’ vision of digitally led social innovation and technocratic governance, as evidenced by secondary sources such as published first-hand accounts, newspaper articles and reports from industry and third sector organisations. We continue by discussing the specific regulatory framework around short-term letting in London and the conditions of operations of Airbnb in the capital, drawing on the analysis of publicly available data gleaned from Airbnb and from the independent online data platform Inside Airbnb. To address different responses to the regulatory challenges of Airbnb in London, we analyse shifts in planning policy and examine their implications through selected qualitative interviews with planning enforcement officers from the four inner city boroughs in London where the issue of short-term letting through digital platforms, and particularly Airbnb, was more acute at the time of the study (2016): Islington, Camden, Royal Borough of Kensington and Chelsea (RBKC) and Westminster. The four boroughs presented key differences. In terms of political alignment, Camden and Islington were Labour-controlled whilst Westminster and RBKC were Conservative-controlled. Although the local housing rental markets differed in absolute terms, they presented similarities in relative terms, for example when comparing the average letting value through a standard tenancy to that of a similar property through a short-term let. For a 1-bedroom flat, the difference was £49 to £150 per day in Islington, while at the highest end, in RBKC, it was £67 to £178 per day. Finally, while all four boroughs showed the highest numbers of properties listed on Airbnb in London, the total amount ranged from 3288 offers in Islington, of which 1831 were entire homes, to over 4700 in Westminster, of which 3284 were entire homes (Inside Airbnb, October 2016). These corresponded to 1.8% and 2.7%, respectively, of the total number of dwellings in each borough (DCLG, 2016). In the latter part of the paper we outline how different planning departments responded to short-term letting through Airbnb and look at how the challenges of enforcing regulations around platform economies reveal the increasing incorporation of digital companies into the management and planning of cities, further developing neoliberal practices of urban governance. We end by examining how ideas of technology-led governance have emerged in response to the discrepancy between data generated by platform economies and the data required to enact and enforce new regulatory frameworks. In the conclusions, industry calls for algorithmic regulations are examined to raise wider question about the implications of sharing economy platforms for urban planning and policy- making. In the latter part of the paper we outline how different planning departments responded to short- term letting through Airbnb and look at how the challenges of enforcing regulations around platform economies reveal the increasing incorporation of digital companies into the management and planning of cities, further developing neoliberal practices of urban governance. We end by examining how ideas of technology-led governance have emerged in response to the discrepancy between data generated by platform economies and the data required to enact and enforce new regulatory frameworks. In the conclusions, industry calls for algorithmic regulations are examined to raise wider question about the implications of sharing economy platforms for urban planning and policy-making. Airbnb and visions of regulatory ‘flattening’ What began as somewhat revolutionary ideas of sharing assets, goods and services, has shifted away from these more convivial exchanges1 to increasingly monetized ones as venture capital firms come to intervene and influence these processes (Slee, 2016). As the aim has shifted away from sharing to profit-making, companies have also sought to scale up their global operations through influencing urban governance structures. The challenge of on-demand provision of services and spaces has been shown to affect labour relations (for example, Deliveroo, TaskRabbit, Butler etc), transport (such as the controversial taxi application Uber) and ways of using urban spaces (for example, JustParking). Platform economy companies position themselves discursively and practically at the forefront of a social and economic revolution. The celebration of web-based sharing technologies as a source of social innovation is often presented as a value-neutral question of connectivity between users and assets through personal ‘empowerment’ (Rachel Botsman, quoted in Slee, 2016). The roots of this narrative can be found in the discourse of informationism emerging in the 1990s around the so-called ‘Internet Revolution’ (Neubauer, 2011). The key claim of informationism was that technological development would decentralise power, making existing nation-state and civil society institutions obsolete and unnecessary. The kernel of this discourse was a prescriptive, celebratory narrative that contrasted ideas of personal empowerment with purported anachronistic state institutions, presenting them as antithetical. As stated by the American conservative commentator Lawrence Kudlow in 1999, “the internet empowers ordinary people and disempowers government” (Kudlow quoted in Neubauer, 2011: 215). An important element of this decentralisation of power through technology was the 1 Many of these sites such as couchsurfing.com began as websites where people would host others in their homes through reputational economies free from monetary exchange. ‘flattening’ of existing place-based specificities (Friedman, 2005; Neubauer, 2011) and the end of “the tyranny of geography” (Slee, 2016). Contrary to Kudlow’s forecast, the exponential development of Information and Communication Technologies and its impact on everyday life has on the contrary opened up an unprecedented degree of incorporation of technology and place-based urban activities. The technological utopianism of Silicon Valley’s digital companies has in fact informed calls to greater government intervention and collaboration, a further instance of the unprecedented role of IT companies in influencing and shaping city governance (Kitchin, 2014). The latest rethinking of the relationship between digital technological innovation and urbanism, often discussed under the rubric of the ‘smart city’, have moreover strongly positioned states and urban government as key institutional actors within the wider digital revolution (Deakin, 2013; Hollands, 2008; Kitchin, 2014). The global ‘scaling up’ of platforms such as Airbnb has crucially raised the question of the role of existing urban policy frameworks and their multiple geographically specific manifestations. On the issue of engaging with specific local policies, the position of platform economy companies is at times expressed publicly with candour. In a 2015 radio show, spokespersons from a range of platform economy companies including Airbnb lamented the ‘patchwork of cities’ regulations’ that they face when they scale up their sharing applications across transport labour and spatial activities.2 Airbnb’s staff in particular identified the existence of place- specific urban governance, both in terms of taxation and in terms of qualification, as the main barrier to implementing their vision. Their wish was for a top-down strategy of ‘model legislation’ transferrable from one city to the next: ‘if we could take one city and do it right there, Portland is our best example in the US, and replicate that, ideally top down […] basically create a model and then scale it. What would be challenging is if every city wants to behave differently’.3 Evident in this approach is a dismissal of geographical specificities through the proposal of a ‘flattening’ vision in which a pilot legislation is scaled up, ‘ideally top down’ to all cities. Appealing to urban units of governance is discussed as a solution to the territorial fragmentation of taxation and planning legislation. The answer for Airbnb has been to encourage mayors and national governments to rethink urban regulation to re-inscribe emerging short-let practices within existing legislations, or to change legislations to accommodate them where they lay outside formal uses. Lobbying work by Airbnb’s Shared Cities Network was launched in fall 2013, leading to the adoption of a ‘Shareable Cities Resolution’ in 2013 (US Conference of Mayors, 2013) and more recently, to the establishment of an Airbnb Mayoral Advisory Board with the aim of helping “other cities embrace home sharing” in the words of its chair and former mayor of Philadelphia, Michael Nutter (reported in Andrews, 2016). Speakers to the radio program also discussed how the situation is different in Europe, where lobbying yielded more unified legislative responses. While in the US ‘every city wants to behave differently’ posing a challenge to their aspiration, “abroad we've seen a lot more progress on this front”, for instance in France and in the United Kingdom, where “the national legislation sets a national policy, but then allows cities to customise it.” In 2013, the British government set up a Round Table on the Sharing Economy with attendees from all the major commercial sharing economy platforms, including Airbnb. As reported by sharing economy 2 ‘Regulation and the Sharing Economy’ radio podcast a16z, with speakers from Airbnb, Instacart, LocalMotion, Lyft, Teespring and Tilt, 15 April 2015. Available https://soundcloud.com/a16z/a16z- podcast-regulation-and-the-sharing-economy [accessed 22 March 2016]. 3 It is worth noting that Portland, Oregon, was heralded by Airbnb CEO Brian Chesky as Airbnb’s first ‘shared city’ in his visual essay “Shared City” (Chesky, 2014). entrepreneur attendee Alex Stephany the approach of the government could be encapsulated by the introductory speech by the then Chancellor of the Exchequer, who addressed participants with the encouragement “tell us what we can do to help you break down barriers” (quoted in Stephany, 2015: 151). Among attendees was Patrick Robinson, Head of European Public Policy for Airbnb. A few months later, in January 2014, the Deregulation Bill had its first reading in the House of Commons. Among the changes introduced by the bill was the ‘deregulation’ of short-term letting in London, which involved the removal of city-specific limits and the introduction of new regulations designed to address and support the online-mediated use of residential properties for hospitality. The transformation of existing legislation and the introduction of new enforcement procedures and the rationale for these raise important questions about the role of local governments and planning officers in the city, but also about the practice of implementing such changes, as will be discussed in further detail in the following section. Short-term letting in London Local governments such as local councils within the United Kingdom have a long history of addressing private and commercial interests, balancing between encouraging industry and implementing the welfare state. Among their various responsibilities is the provision of social services, housing and the licensing of economic opportunities. The provision and regulation of affordable housing by the government, for example, has seen shifts over time. While this is a complex discussion, it is worthwhile noting a few historical points here to trace key elements of affordable housing provision. In the post war period, there was considerable expansion of state- subsidized council housing which eventually gave way to a decline in municipal and national house building, the privatisation of existing stock through Right to Buy schemes and its overall residualisation (Murie, 2016). This shift was met with a system of direct tenant subsidies for both social rented and private rented tenants. This too has come under assault in the recent years as the costs of subsidies have increased, particularly in the capital where housing costs are extremely high (Hamnett, 2010). In London, the stress on affordable housing supply was exacerbated by more lucrative practices of short-term letting, both for tourism and for low-income residents. In an effort to balance both the affordable housing shortages in the capital and the demands of tourism, national legislation was implemented in 1973 that made London an exception within the country. This legislation, titled the Greater London Council (General Powers) Act of 1973 prohibited short-term lets – defined as less than 90 days in the calendar year – for properties or parts of properties in the city. Those wishing to let properties for short periods would have to apply for planning permission for a change of use.4 5One of the rationales behind this was a consideration that the change of a space from long-term residential to short-term vacation rental would lead to the concomitant increase in traffic, noise, nuisance in a neighbourhood or building, affecting the security of residents and the character of neighbourhoods. On the basis of this policy, London boroughs have attempted, in varying degrees, to monitor and enforce regulation against short-term lets that take place without change of use permission. 4 The change of use would be from residential use (C3 in UK planning law) to use as a hotel (C1). 5 Change of use may also be prohibited or limited by tenancy agreements. In Westminster council for example, a team of six officers has previously deployed a strategy of door-to-door inspections to detect infractions. Landlords found renting their properties illegally have been issued with warnings and fines. While this system has been far from perfect, it has helped to construct a semblance of control over unsanctioned short-term letting within the council boundaries (Holman et al., 2017). In less-resourced councils, the ability to enforce the law with regards to short-term lets has been even more limited as will be discussed in greater detail below. With the advent of the platform economy, and particularly Airbnb, local councils have continued their regulatory oversight of such activities as well, in line with their mandate. In addition to reasons outlined above, council officers have also offered arguments for regulating illegal or informal use of residential property in order to protect an already overstretched rental property supply, particularly in areas characterised by high living costs. On the basis of this policy, London boroughs have attempted, in varying degrees, to monitor and enforce regulation against short-term lets that take place without change of use permission. In Westminster council, for example, a team of six officers has previously deployed a strategy of door-to-door inspections to detect infractions. Landlords found renting their properties illegally have been issued with warnings and fines. While this system has been far from perfect, it has helped to construct a semblance of control over unsanctioned short-term letting within the council boundaries (Holman et al., 2017). In less-resourced councils, the ability to enforce the law with regards to short-term lets has been even more limited, as will be discussed in greater detail below. With the advent of the platform economy, and particularly Airbnb, local councils have continued their regulatory oversight of such activities as well, in line with their mandate. In addition to the reasons outlined above, council officers have also offered arguments for regulating illegal or informal use of residential property in order to protect an already overstretched rental property supply, particularly in areas characterised by high living costs. Deregulating short-term letting This is an opportunity for the Capital to catch up with the 21st Century way of living. (Department for Communities and Local Government, 2015) Since 2012, when Airbnb first entered the London market, it has gathered strength at increasing pace, from an estimate of 14,000 listings in June 2015 (Quattrone et al., 2016) to over 49,000 in October 2016 (Inside Airbnb London), with greater concentration and impact in inner London boroughs. Faced with this growth, in 2014, the central government began consulting on the issue with local authorities and platform economy companies. In September 2014, it commissioned Debbie Wosskow, CEO of the home-sharing online platform Love Home Swap, to write a review of the sharing economy and to make recommendations on ‘how the UK can become the global centre for the sharing economy’. In recognizing London’s chronic undersupply of long-term residential properties, and referring to the regulation of Airbnb and other short-term let platforms, one of the key recommendations of the report was that “egregious breaches of regulation – for example, letting out a large number of rooms through sharing economy platforms, but not complying with tax and regulatory requirements – must be dealt with firmly” (Wosskow, 2014: 28). In March 2015 the Department for Business, Innovation & Skills responded to the report by outlining a point by point response to the recommendations. In terms of Airbnb hosts breaching planning regulation, the response stated that change of use would continue requiring planning permission and that ‘[i]f a change of use occurs without planning permission, the local planning authority can consider taking enforcement action’ (ibid: 13). Later in the paragraph, the recommendation about firm action against breaches is evaded, as the response continues: ‘Enforcement action is discretionary, and local planning authorities should act proportionately in responding to suspected breaches of planning control […] and take action where it is appropriate to do so’ (Department for Business, Innovation and Skills, 2015: 13, emphasis added). The stress on the discretionary dimension and appropriateness of enforcement action seem to indicate a desire to leave ample margin for negotiations. Here, as in the opening quote, the vision of regulatory flattening brought about by digital companies is accepted and promoted by the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills in the name of progress and interurban competition. In the Deregulation Act passed in March 2015, the government proposed and implemented the removal of ‘red tape’ by enabling short-term letting without change of use if under 90 cumulative days in a calendar year. In doing so, it disregarded objections raised by local councils and MPs to relaxing the safeguards that had thus far been put in place (Holman et al., 2017). The rationale for remaking regulations on the question of short-term letting is evident in the Department for Communities and Local Government’s report ‘Promoting the sharing economy in London’ (February 2015). In it, deregulation is argued to ‘…enable Londoners to participate in the sharing economy and benefit from recent innovations in information technology by letting out either a spare room or their whole house in the same way as other residents across the country’ (Department for Communities and Local Government, 2015). The official rhetoric in favour of sharing economy platforms expressed here draws on the discourse of individual empowerment (Martin, 2016) while neglecting the role played by corporate players and businesses (Slee, 2016). While the report claims that the policy is “aimed at helping residents, and not providing opportunities for the commercial sector” (DCLG, 2015), data published by the independent website Inside Airbnb in 2015 and 2016 revealed a different picture on the ground. Contrary to the benign discourse of Londoners using Airbnb to earn income from spare rooms, the data showed that 51.3% of all listings in the capital6 were entire homes, and that 41.3% were multi- listings - that is multiple listings for a single host.7 In London as in other European cities (Sans and Quaglieri, 2016), multi-listings have been taken as an indication of the encroachment of professional letting into the short-term let platform economy (Finck and Ranchordas, 2016; Slee, 2016) with potential wider implications for the rental housing market (McCoy and Sigee, 2016). The expansion of sharing platforms and particularly of the situation in which some propertied individuals and organizations amass increasing numbers of properties to put on the short-term let market for high profits have given rise to concern among planning enforcement officers across the four boroughs studied. Corroborating the data noted above, officers in the inner-city borough of Westminster for instance have commented that, contrary to the rhetoric of empowering individual property owners, their own evidence revealed a large proportion of business and profit-making uses of properties. This created a friction with the duties and 6 Inside Airbnb London, http://insideairbnb.com/london/ [accessed 24th August 2016]. 7 Lower estimates have been stated in the Supplementary Written Evidence from the British Hospitality Association 1 that in London at least 40% of all listings are “professional hosts running pseudo-hotels” (British Hospitality Federation, 2016).
Description: